CIVILIZATION began with exchange, and exchange began with barter. Barter means
the exchange of things for things, with each transaction complete in itself,
leaving no claim or obligation by either trader. Obviously, such transactions
require contact of two traders, each of whom has something the other wants.
Such contacts are not easy to make, and an escape from this limited exchange
method had to be found to permit man to raise his standard of living beyond
that of bare necessities.
The first device resorted to was to adopt, for a criterion of value, some
commodity that was in common use. A list of the commodities adopted in this way
at various times and places would include salt, hides, grains, cattle, tobacco,
metals, and so forth. The trader accepting these found them useful not only to
himself, but on account of their general acceptance, he was assured that he
could use them to secure desired commodities in exchange. This was the first
step in the process of liberating exchange, a process that would culminate with
money. A refinement in this important first step came about with the adoption
of precious metals such as gold and silver as intermediating commodities. This
manifested a greater emphasis upon usefulness for exchange rather than for
consumption, and marked the final phase of whole barter, or value-for-value
exchange, before the dawn of money.
Because of the use of precious metals as the last and highest phase of whole
barter exchange, the next step in the direction and harbinger of money was the
introduction of a promise to deliver these metals. The belief persists to this
day that money, to be sound, must promise the delivery of gold or silver. The
essential quality of money, however, is its promise to deliver value in any
commodity at the choice of the holder. But in spite of the specification of a
given commodity stipulated in the promise, the promise came closer to being
money than anything previous because it involved a time interval between the
first transaction and the final completion of the exchange, when value has been
received on both sides. It introduced also the element of faith.
The need for money has always been far in advance of the implements available
for utilizing it. Because the need was and always is so urgent, the trader has
accepted anything that has offered the prospect of effecting non-direct barter
exchange. In doing so, he has exposed himself to the devices of the charlatan
as well as the sincere reformer. He has had no rationale to guide him. The only
logic he has been able to employ has been to choose the better media when two
or more have been available.
Why has man consistently endeavored to escape simple barter when, because of its
very simplicity, it has offered security against deception while monetary
systems have invariably betrayed him? Why must man have money? It is neither a
tool of production nor a product. It is neither food, raiment, housing nor
adornment. It has no value, yet it is indispensable to modern man.
Why indispensable? Because man's wealth producing potentialities through
specialization of labor cannot be exploited unless the exchange of goods and
services can be split in two parts, with one trader receiving value and the
other receiving only the prospect of value. Therefore what man has been
striving for is the opportunity to acquire without coincidentally surrendering
value. If he must complete the exchange in one transaction, he is reduced to
simple barter, and simple barter requires him to find someone who has what he
wants and wants what he has. To do this requires so much time and effort that
he loses what he might otherwise gain from the specialization of labor.
Visualize two persons facing each other, one holding a value that the other
desires, and the other holding nothing of value. How can they do business?
Obviously the empty-handed, would-be trader must have some means of inducing
the possessing trader to transfer the desired value. If he asks what the
possessor would like in exchange and promises to deliver this desired commodity
at a later time, and if this promise is accepted and the possessor surrenders
his value, the promisor has established credit. But the transaction is not a
monetary transaction, even though the promisee accepts a written evidence of
the promise. Here, then, we should pause to comprehend that money and credit
are not synonymous. The promisor has not gained the freedom of money, because
he must now seek and find and deliver the specific commodity pledged. The
barter transaction has been only partly split, by the introduction of the time
interval. To invoke the facility of monetary exchange, the would-be trader must
deliver requisitionary power upon some unidentified trader or traders who can
and will surrender an equivalent value at the holder's option.
The utilization of money as the medium of exchange does not mean departure from
barter. It is but a method of splitting barter completely in two halves. The
acceptor of money gives value therefore but receives only a promise of value,
which, when conveyed to a subsequent seller, requisitions his half of the
split-barter transaction. Introducing a time element into barter and giving the
acceptor the power to requisition his half from any trader and in any
commodity, at any time, is what expedites and multiplies exchange, thus
releasing more and greater variety of production and hence raising living
standards.
While money is the liberator of exchange, it is also the vehicle of human trust
and confidence. Its substance is the pledge that he who takes will also give.
This pledge of faith is the basis of the power to issue money. In simple terms,
it means that he who would issue money to cover his purchases must be prepared
to redeem his pledge by selling. In other words, persons who enter a monetary
exchange agree to give and take things in trade, at the market price, on the
tender of the monetary instrument from any quarter. Thus every trader relies
upon the pledge of the issuer that he will honor his issue on demand.
A society accustomed to trade on the basis of its faith in its money is
vulnerable to deception as it never was on the whole barter system. It is
imperative, therefore, that man master money, so that he can assure the
fidelity of the promise implicit in what he accepts as money, and can not only
exclude from the issue power all unworthy of it, but can admit to it all of
those who are worthy of it—including those now excluded under the
existing political monetary system.
If money is to fulfill its function as the liberator of exchange, it must be
protected from pollution by false issuers, and it must also be free to draw its
supply from all worthy sources. The broader its base, the higher can be its
apex and the greater its service to mankind.
MONEY THE ORGANIZER
For economic and social advancement, men must specialize their labor and
facilitate their exchanges. To reap the fruits of this operation, they must
organize in cooperative groups even though widely dispersed. Money fulfills
this function through its circulation. The whole cooperative scheme is made up
of monetary circles, tying together men who mostly are strangers to one another
but who have a common interest in the cooperative circle. Money organizes these
circles of cooperators on a democratic basis, for each in turn is able to
choose his supplier. While each has contact with and knowledge of only the ones
immediately to the right and left of him, i.e. the ones to whom he sold and
from whom he bought, the circle formed by the money that passed through his
hands may involve scores or hundreds of others, all of whom are essential to
the successful operation of his exchange.
Let us take a hypothetical example. An Ohio clothing merchant borrows a sum of
money from a bank which he sends to a New York clothing manufacturer, who sends
it to an Australian wool grower, who sends it to a supplier in England, who
sends it to his supplier in Argentina, who sends it to a French supplier, who
sends it to a Swedish supplier, who sends it to a supplier in the East Indies,
who sends it to a Cuban supplier, and so forth until it gets back to the
merchant in Ohio who started the circle. Such a circle is very unlikely,
because it is confined to wholesale traders without the money getting into the
hands of employees through payrolls at some point. This was avoided in the
example because the ramifications would have been too complex to follow.
The point intended to be conveyed by the example is that the Ohio merchant
started and finished a monetary circle that went around the world and effected
exchanges among traders who were strangers to each other, except that each knew
his supplier and his customer. Of such circles the economic and social fabric
is woven. Visualize the intricate interlacing of economic interest and activity
if some or all of the factors in the circle borrowed money from their banks and
started new monetary circles of their own, and contemplate how essential to the
economy it is that this power to issue be widely held.
We are apt to think that money circulates indefinitely, but this is a mistake.
Money has a life span that lasts from issue to redemption. This does not imply
that individual issues are identified. It means that an equivalent amount is
normally retired by the issuer through payment of his bank "loan,"
and thus the money is retired. Nor is there a definite life span. Some monetary
circles are longer than others. The length is determined by when in the circle
a buyer is found for the goods or services offered by the issuer. Also, an
issuer can balance his account by retiring money from circles other than the
one that he initiated He discharges his obligation to the economy by retiring
from any quarter whatsoever an equal amount of money as compared to his own
issue.
Money is the organizer of true cooperators, i.e. those who meet competition, and
the eliminator of those who do not. Thus it raises standards of living and
culture ever to higher levels. It is the greatest civilizing agent available to
man, and his greatest liberator. An eloquent statement of the social order, as
developed through the use of money in exchange, is given by Spencer Heath:
The social organization raises the individual member from the state of being as
a creature, dependent on and arbitrarily enslaved to environment, into
freedom and abundance, dependent on but not enslaved by the society of which he
is a functioning part. Without the services of his fellow social units, his
whole life is ruled by the exigencies of environment and circumstance. His life
is determined without regard to his choice or will, and he must obey, under
penalty of his death and the extinction of his race. But when he enters into
the social relationship of serving many persons and being by many served, the
productivity, the creativeness of this golden rule of exchange lifts him out of
an almost completely necessitous state and into a relative abundance that
relieves him from the compulsions of an un-socialized environment and endows
him with wide alternatives and options for the exercise of his spontaneous
will. And when he has entered, his acts of service and exchange are by
voluntary contracts under consent of his own will in accord with that of his
fellow man—the 'social will'—as its unforced expressions arise in
the forums of exchange. Out of the fruitfulness of the services performed and
exchanged, this as yet too limited mutual freedom and accord of individual
wills, the energies of men are emancipated to activities not prescribed by
necessities from without but by preference and choice—by realizations of
the intrinsic and spontaneous will. For this gift of freedom to its members,
the society is requited with all spontaneous researches, discoveries, and
recreations and the practice and enjoyment of the esthetic and creative arts.*
* Citadel, Market and Altar, The Heather Foundation, 1957,
page 196 (from the book draft prior to publication).
SYSTEM AND UNIT
The word "money" has two meanings: the concept and the instrument that
manifests the concept. The monetary concept is a bookkeeping concept and system
of split-barter trading in which money springs from a debit and is returned by
an offsetting credit. The debits represent money issued and the credits money
accepted. The monetary instrument may specify the transferee, as with a check,
or it may take the form of currency (bills and coins), which specifies no
transferee and is valid in the hands of any holder.
The moving instruments evidencing the bookkeeping process need have no intrinsic
value. They are floating ledger items that, on reaching the authorizing bank
which acts as central bookkeeper and clearing house for the system, cause the
transfer of their sum from the account of the transferer to the transferee. The
system is thus a reflection of and dependent upon the private book records of
traders. When a trader sends through the monetary system a money manifest, he
figuratively tears a page from his ledger to permit the entry to pass through
the system.
The bank has no power to issue money in any form. It merely authorizes traders
to do so by incurring debits on the books of the system. The only way that such
an issue of money can be effected is for the issuer to write an order on the
authorizing bank. Thus the check becomes the initial form of money. If it is
desired that the credit be transferred to a specific person, the check so
states. If it is intended to convey the credit to unidentified persons, it
orders the bank to supply currency. Thus we see that checks are the initiating
form of money, and that currency is but a transformation. It should be noted
also that the currency is as much the issue of the check writer who
requisitioned it as was his check. In effect, he merely ordered the bank to
certify his credit by issuing instruments in the name of the bank, who in
exchange for assuming the liability acquired a credit from the check writer's
account. To think of currency as money and checks as "substitute
money" is profoundly mistaken.
The authorizing bank has power neither to issue nor to loan money, though it
seems at a cursory glance to exert both these powers. It loans neither its
capital, its surplus or its depositors' funds. It merely authorizes the
borrower, so-called, to increase the money supply, and its deposits show an
immediate increase in the sum of the so-called loan. The currency that the bank
gives out may bear a bank's name or that of the Government, but it is
nevertheless the issue of the writer of the check that requisitioned it.
Money, as we have seen, has no value, and this is not any less true of currency.
Money merely permits value in the abstract, dissociated from any specific
commodity, to be exchanged for an equivalent value in any commodity at any time
or place, at the behest of the holder. While metallic coins are useful as
currency for small transactions or making change, the fact that they may have
intrinsic value does not, therefore, make them superior to paper as money.
Indeed, the reverse is true. For to the extent of their intrinsic value, they
are not money at all, but instruments of whole barter. They are only monetary
(split-barter) instruments for the balance of their face sum. A commodity can
never act as money, for the very purpose of money is to obviate the necessity
of transfer of value from the buyer to the seller and, thusly, to escape the
limitation of whole barter and gain the freedom and facility of split barter.
As money is the mathematics of value, so a sum of money is expressed in terms of
an abstract unit of value. Such a value unit might be arrived at initially by
equating it with the value of any commodity or group of commodities a given
point in time. Whatever value might be selected in this way then becomes the
unit, or the figure 1. To establish it as the monetary unit, however, there
must be actual exchanges, where under buyers issue and sellers accept the issue
on the basis selected. Such actual exchanges establish the power of the unit,
and the acceptors, i.e. the sellers, then have a fixed power established in
their minds and undertake to get in exchange for the units as much or greater
value than they gave. Thus a monetary unit is established by the precedent of
actual exchanges and in no other way. No law or authority can give a fixed
power to a monetary unit. It must be fixed in actual competitive trade.
At the inception of a new monetary unit, it would be theoretically correct to
launch it at par with some item or items of commodity value. Since we already
have operating monetary units in existence, however, it would only be necessary
in practice to base a new unit upon some such existing unit or fraction or
multiple. For if we made up a market basket of some or all commodities that are
now passing in exchange and tabulated, say, their dollar prices, we would find
that one dollar represented some fraction of the whole. In other words, all
existing monetary units are already based upon a market basket, and a new
monetary unit would be based upon a market basket by accepting an existing unit
as the criterion for the new. That is how the American dollar was established,
by introducing it at par with the Spanish dollar then current in the States.
Thereafter, it followed its own course. The Spanish dollar has long since
passed out, but it provided the springboard for what has proven to be the most
stable unit in the world.
Bearing in mind that value can only be determined by competition, we might now
define money as follows:
Money is an obligation expressed in terms of a value unit and issued by a buyer
in exchange for value from a seller. It is transferable and acceptable to other
sellers for equivalent value, and is ultimately redeemed for equivalent value
by the issuer.
|